Thursday 7 March 2019

A Partial Reply to Jamelle Bouie, for Brandon

In response to this article, sent to me by my friend Brandon: https://www.nytimes.com/2019/02/28/opinion/the-electoral-college.html?fbclid=IwAR3DLH9mrhbc-wrLjiBscslURyglvGeCjJ7l6zoYrQxR-8DqNnEZBvXPYDE.


I think it's always important to give the best hearing we can to anything we want to change - it's the Fence Principle. We ought to know why a fence exists before it's taken down. Bouie does offer *an* explanation of why the Electoral College, but I'm not sure it's entirely accurate. Let me explain what I mean.

1) He doesn't really address the concept of state as corporate political bodies, which was a central aspect of the logic involved in your nation's confederation, as you'll know even better than I. Presumably he rejects the idea that nations can have within them distinct corporate political bodies other than the national government - that is, he's a form of absolutist. But he doesn't explain this, and it's a big concept in Anglo-American law (e.g. it's part of the logic of why a limited company can exist distinct from its owners).

2) Bouie quotes from the Convention on the EC, and takes a distinct view that it came about over against the popular vote because of slavery - that is, the lack of suffrage meaning slave states would have a lower proportional voting power than free states. Madison (as per the quote) certainly considered this one reason in its favour, but there's much more beyond that, and I think Bouie makes a serious oversight in limiting his survey to a few slave state proponents. Smaller free (or functionally free) states like Connecticut and New Jersey supported it for the same reasons as they supported Congressional apportionment (for which, see point 3). Hamilton, a federalist from a large functionally free state, was a strong proponent, for various reasons, especially based on the election-by-district system he and Madison supported (i.e. you vote an elector, not a president, who then represents you in a free college election). He thought electing people for a specific purpose at one point gave them a particular mandate, prevented permanent factional cabals (as you get with permanent legislatures electing presidents or whatever), emphasizes the importance of local knowledge, and more easily prevented foreign influence given it was time-limited and the identity of the electors wasn't guaranteed beforehand.

3) Now, the question is related to the issue of state-proportional representation in the Senate, and it's worth looking at how that came about to understand some of the reasons the Electoral College "Fence" is there. Of course, in the EC, the relative power of the states is much less than in Congress - North Dakota and Delaware have 3 votes each, whilst California has 55! But Connecticut fought for both the Electoral College and state-proportional representation in the upper house of a bicameral legislature. The Virginia Plan argued for a population-proportional bicameral legislature, but with differing forms of election in each case; the opposing New Jersey Plan, backed by other small states like Delaware, was for a state-proportional unicameral legislature. Generally speaking, it was *Southern* states which favoured the Virginia Plan - their population was expected to grow quicker than nominally larger states like New York, and they had the opportunity of expansion over the Appalachians (which, unsurprisingly, Delaware and New Jersey did not!). New York, on the other hand, broadly favoured population-proportionality, because despite being large, feared being outpaced. (It should be said that Hamilton of New York backed population-proportionality.) The Connecticut Compromise (again, a Northern State's representatives put it forward) gave the US its current legislature - bicameral with mixed proportions of representation.

(Points 1+2+3 Summary - Bouie argues that it was fundamentally the Southern states which conspired to form the Electoral College so as to let them count slaves in their "voting" population without granting them suffrage. In fact, it was various states, notably smaller Northern states, desiring to retain their corporate individuality, and supported by those Framers who saw specific merits in the system of an Electoral College, which pushed through the current system, and who largely pushed through the related state-proportional Senate. Incidentally, for a look at the proportion-by-state of members of the Convention, see: http://law2.umkc.edu/faculty/projects/ftrials/conlaw/marryff.html. Very insightful.)

4) Finally, Bouie argues that the Electoral College currently benefits Republicans (and there is, I suspect, an unspoken connection here to his theory of slave states conspiring to fix the system). Of course, you might argue it literally did in 2016; Trump won a majority of EC votes despite losing the popular vote. And it's fair to show the rough workings and see that this is the case, when we look at states with a win-percentage that rounds off to 5% or less (I pick swing states as an itemization of the general rule as Bouie focusses on the advantages of abolishing swing states).
Contested States
Arizona (11) – 3.5% win for Trump
Colorado (9) – 4.9% win for Clinton
Florida (29) – 1.2% win for Trump
Georgia (16) – 5.1% win for Trump
Maine At-Large (2) – 3% win for Clinton
Michigan (16) – 0.25% win for Trump
Minnesota (10) – 1.5% win for Clinton
Nebraska 2nd (1) – 2.2% win for Trump
Nevada (6) – 2.4% win for Clinton
New Hampshire (4) – 0.35% for Clinton
North Carolina (15) – 3.65% win for Trump
Pennsylvania (20) – 0.7% win for Trump
Virginia (13) – 5.3% win for Clinton
Wisconsin (10) – 0.75% win for Trump

Trump won 118 Electoral Votes in 8 Contested States (or part-States)
Clinton won 44 Electoral Votes in 6 Contested States (or part-States)

One thing that comes to mind is that the swing states that swung it for Trump are of varied size – larger (Florida, Pennsylvania) and medium (Arizona, Georgia, Michigan, North Carolina, Wisconsin) – but not small states, which is why Clinton didn't receive the benefit of the large number of votes for her in those states. However, though this does show that the Electoral College (or, really, any FPTP system at all like this) does make individual votes less valuable and makes some constituencies/states/whatever more vital to campaign in, it doesn't fit the general pattern (not, in fairness, Bouie's explicit thrust, though perhaps an implication) of complaining about a mad minority of red-state voters determining things for everyone else. They're not small nor necessarily red states; Obama won 6 of the 8 vital Trump swing states in 2012. They are broadly representative states of the “whole” of America – with large cities, wealthy sections, and rural populations, all in far better proportion than, say, New York State or California (which are also very mixed, as Bouie mentions). It'll require a bit more reflection and thought, but it seems significant to me that the very thing used here against the Electoral College – a disproportionate result in years like 2016 – actually allows us to observe a different kind of proportionality.

The other thing that comes to mind here is that it seems hard to demonstrate that the system need especially favour Republicans. (A historical digression here allows us to observe that whilst four of the five popular-vote-losers to win are Republicans, two were so during the Third Party System, and so with a rather different policy base.) The last two popular-vote-losing Presidents have been Republicans, but the massive swing in Electoral Votes based on small state-specific swings has benefited both sides – see 1960, 1992, or 1996 for examples of significantly disproportionate Democratic victories, for instance. That's not an argument in favour of the Electoral College – but an argument against conspiracy theorizing about it as a GOP tool.

5) I think Bouie's point about the electoral machinery focussing far more on some states than on others is valid and relevant, though it can be framed as significant even if one wanted to retain the state structure – it overvalues some states at the expense of others. Of course, in a pure popular vote, it's not as if certain swing groups wouldn't be targeted by the major candidates; they might not be geographically concentrated, but suburban women and working-class men would still be vital constituencies, and it's arguable that the electoral bribes offered them would be even greater under a purely proportional system. This is natural in any vote-based system. In a different context, some Senators were more key in terms of pressure group activity during the Kavanaugh hearings – Manchin, Tester, Flake, Collins, Murkowski – than others. After all, no-one was sending extra letters to Mazie Hirono or Lindsey Graham.

CONCLUSION: I don't think either Bouie's article or my little response here can fully “answer” the topic, but I hope we can ask better questions, at least. Why did a coalition of states delegations, both slave and free, both small and large, enshrine state-proportionality in the Constitution – both for the Electoral College an the Senate? With that answered, we may ask: are states legitimate constituent and mediating parts? If they are, why? If not, why not? We can also ask: is the disproportionality of the Electoral College necessarily bad, and even if Americans chose to change it, is there anything it tells us that is valuable and worth preserving in any future system? Finally, as we can see that a purely proportional Presidential vote would be open to special interest campaigning in the same way as the Electoral College (even if we debate which is better or worse), we can ask: is there any effective way to limit the exaggerated power of special interest groups in any voting-system, be it direct, proportional, delegated, or whatever?